Noer Fauzi Rachman
The author thanks Nancy Peluso, Louise Fortmann, John Bruce, Clint Carroll and Megan Ybarra for insightful comments of earlier forms of the paper, and also to Megan Ybarra and Ann Hawkins for consulting on the English language of some part of the paper.
What we call land is an element of nature inextricably interwoven with
man’s institutions. To isolate it and form a market out of it was perhaps
the weirdest of all undertakings of our ancestors.
(Polanyi, 1944:178)
Contemporary development schemes, whether in Southeast Asia or elsewhere,
require the creation of state spaces where the government can reconfigure
the society and the economy of those that are to be developed
(Scott 1998: 187)
I. Introduction
In 2005, more than ten years after funding three land administration
projects in Indonesia since 1994,[1] the World Bank (WB) confidently published “Indonesia Policy Brief.
Ideas for the Future: Land Policy, Management and Administration.” The
policy brief justifies land projects by identifying the following problems
in Indonesia’s current land policies:
· Efficient and sustainable resource use: Unless land rights are clearly
defined (as individual property rights), it is difficult to provide those
who use the land with an incentive to do so in a sustainable and efficient
manner and prevent serious degradation of resources.
· Investment climate: Businesses small and large require land to operate.
Non-transparent, corrupt, and inefficient systems of land administration
and allocation constitute serious obstacles to conducting and expanding
business.
· Credit markets access: The development of efficient financial markets will critically depend on the ability to use land as collateral and transfer it at low cost.
· Revenues for local governments: Unless at least some part of local
governments’ spending is covered by its own revenue, it will be difficult
to establish accountability and prevent decentralization from degenerating
into a rent-seeking competition. Land taxes and land-related charges are
ideal sources of such revenue.
· Accountability and transparency: In most countries, more than half of a
households’ wealth is in land and real estate. If the system to administer
it is perceived to be corrupt, overstaffed, and not trustworthy, it will
be difficult to maintain confidence in the rule of law and broader
competence of the state.
· Social safety net: Over and above its importance for economic
development, land access is a critical safety net for millions of people
that can help prevent destitution. Insecure land tenure can seriously
undermine this and with it the ability of poor people to move out of
poverty.”[2]
Most of these claims are not unique. The Bank’s recipe for Indonesia’s land
problem – which is also created by the Bank -- has been directed by
particular project framework, i.e. pro-market land administrations,
managements and policies. Of course there are some differences – for
example, if we compare the Indonesia Land Administration Project (ILAP) to
the Thailand Land Titling Project (TLTP).[3] But, as explained by the WB staff, their basic ingredients are
typically: (i) legal, regulatory and policy reform; (ii) institutional
reform; (iii) systematic land registration (first-time titling); (iv)
support for on-demand titling and development of subsequent land
transactions; (v) land valuation; (vi) improved service delivery for land
agencies; and (vii) capacity building for government, private sector and
academe (Bell, 2006).
I will argue that the WB Indonesia land projects are part of global
systematic effort to promote pro-market land regularization. The processes
to reform land administrations, managements and policies include: providing
money through loans and grants, deploying experts/consultants, producing
authoritative knowledge and expertise, creating epistemic communities, and
last but not least, generating demand for “land administration” services.
The WB’s land projects and its proponents have propagated market ideology,
and used benevolent rhetoric to convince its government-clients. In this
paper, I will dismantle the rhetoric and show consequences of the real
practice of the land registration, its larger institutional framework and
hidden agendas of pro-market land policies. In doing so, I will use the
conceptual framework offered by Bello, Cunningham and Rau, who propose
that
“What usually occurs is a much more complex social process in
which ideology mediates between interests and policy. An
ideology is a belief-system – a set of theories, beliefs, and myths with
some internal coherence – that seeks to universalize the interests of one
social sector to the whole community. In market ideology, for instance,
freeing market forces from state restraints is said to work to the good not
only of [big] business, but also to that of the whole community. Transmitted
through social institutions such as universities, corporations, churches or
parties, an ideology is internalized by large number of people, but
especially by members of the social groups whose interests it principally
expresses. An ideology thus informs the actions of many individuals and
groups, but it becomes a significant force only when certain conditions
coincide (Bello et al 1994:3).”
That conceptual framework, my familiarity with the WB’s Indonesia land
projects,[4] and my understanding on magnitude of the land administration project
across the world, lead me to argue that this global systematic attempt have
consequences as follows: (a) the creation of a huge land registration
business, and (b) reinforcing the existing unequal land distribution, and in
the long run tend to create a new concentration of land in the hand of
speculator, elites and large business on the one hand, and a new
dispossessed smallholders on the other hand.
II. Benevolent rhetoric and characterization of Indonesia’s land
problems
Open almost any official publication on Indonesia’s land “problems”
produced by the World Bank (WB) and you are likely to find it starting
with the same simple and purposive image. A 1994 WB report, “Indonesia:
Environment and Development,” provides a typical case. The question of
Indonesia’s land management almost invariably is introduced as highly
complex, in part due to a lack of clarity in the legal framework for land
acquisitions and in part due to the complicated bureaucratic procedures
and the rent-seeking mechanisms that are involved. These publications also
state that “land markets are not well developed”, and that this “constrains the allocation of land to its highest and
best use”. One main agenda is to establish more effective land markets:
“to improve efficiency and achieve “highest and best use” of land, rely
more on market forces. Specifically, to strengthen ability of land markets
to function by: clarifying and simplifying the legal framework; expediting
land titling and registration; improving the availability of land
information; ‘moving to market prices’ for development purposes; and
reviewing current practices of land acquisition permits” (World Bank
1994:207).[5]
The current example is the World Bank’s 2005 “Indonesia Policy Brief: Ideas
for the Future. Land Policy, Management and Administration:”
“… the magnitude of the challenge in comparison with other countries:
While Indonesia has an estimated 80 million parcels of land, only 17
million are registered, implying that 63 million lack legal
protection. Recognizing occupancy (possession) as evidence of land ownership and
accepting informal evidence for it, e.g. tax receipts combined with
testimony by neighbors could greatly increase tenure security for poor
people, formalize millions of informal land transfers and thus eliminate
an enormous source of conflict, and improve incentives for investment on
the large areas which ongoing efforts at formal land registration will not
be able to cover in the foreseeable future.” (Italics added by NFR)
It is not surprising to one who is familiar with the foreign aid business
(e.g. Hancock 1989, George 1992) that the WB always legitimizes its projects
under the rhetoric of utilitarianism, which is a philosophy originally
proposed by Jeremy Bentham that explicitly argues that the moral worth of an
action is solely determined by its contribution to overall utility. In the
2004 Land Management and Policy Development Project (LMPDP) in Indonesia,
they state that the “overall goal of the project is to contribute to
government programs in achieving poverty reduction, economic growth and
promote full utilization of land resources in a sustainable manner” (World
Bank 2004:3).
Another trope that the Bank uses to legitimize their projects is claiming
that their projects are solely based on requests from or at least in
negotiation with their client-governments. They always reproduce
their legitimacy by claiming merely to serve their clients. In their first
study report on land issues in Indonesia, “Indonesia, Land Resource
Management and Planning” (1991), they start the preface with strong sentence
that this “document has been prepared at the request of the Government of
Indonesia to address some of the emerging issues and challenges in the land
markets, resource planning, and management” (World Bank 1991:v). LASA, a
consortium of land administration consultants from Australia, and Indonesia
National Land Agency (NLA) claim that the 1991 “Indonesia: Land Resource
Management and Planning”
“was received well by the GOI [Government of Indonesia], and during
discussion on the report, GOI requested the Bank to prepare a project that
would address some of the important and impending issues concerning
management and planning of land resources. Based on the request, a World
Bank mission visited Indonesia in April and May 1992 to identify components
and relevant issues in order to identify the components and preparation
requirements of the proposed Land Administration Project. It was agreed
between GOI and the World Bank that the project, which could be the first in a series of Bank projects [in Indonesia] designed to focus on land-related issues, would basically
concentrate on improving land administration, especially the aspects of land
titling/registration and the related institutional framework” (National Land
Agency and Land Administration Systems Australia 1993:
20, Italics added by NFR).
Unsurprisingly, a high-level Indonesian government official absorbed the
ideas with its multiple agendas and he re-promoted that the idea is the
best, and in his turn he amplifies these as the government’s policies. The
Head of the NLA states:
“During 36 years since the enactment of Basic Agrarian Law (Act No. 5 Year
1960) and Government Regulation No. 10 Year 1961 concerning Land
Registration, the cadastre has only been able to register around 12 million
land parcels and titles. But, during only 6 years after the enactment of
Government Regulation No. 24 Year 1997 concerning Land Registration
that I have to admit is an outcome of the Bogor Declaration,[6] the cadastre has successfully registered around 13 million land
parcels and titles through systematic and sporadic registration. The systematic one had been conducted through an adjudication process
and with the assistances of the World Bank, the Australian International
Development Assistance Bureau (AIDAB), and the Land Administration System
Australia (LASA) within the Indonesian Land Administration Project
(ILAP).
In terms of the numbers, this outcome is significant. Nevertheless, the challenge is (sic) still confronts us today and in the future, because we still have around
60 million land parcels have not been registered yet. To deal with this challenge, beginning in the fiscal year of 2005, we will
continue to develop the cadastre through a new project called the Indonesian
Land Management and Policy Development Programs (ILMPDP), with also the
assistance of the World Bank and International Development Association.”
(Nasution 2004:2-3, Italics added by NFR)”
The Government of Indonesia (GOI) is not only a passive
recipient. The ILAP is also the GOI’s project. Sujana Royat,
Director for Spatial Planning and Land Management - National Development
Planning Agency (Bappenas), enthusiastically stated that “the Indonesian
Land Policy Reform is one of the national development priorities,” and he
looks for assistance from the donor community such as “supports to the
policy, strategies, and action programs, supports to laws and regulations
improvement, establishment of land system; land tenure, land registrations,
land titling, etc., land information system, land services for the poor,
capacity building on land management and administration, joint research on
land policy issues, including creation of a sort of land policy institute,
specific studies and policy research on customary land and laws, civil
society empowerment, establishment of national or regional land forums,
supports to stakeholders, such as; NGOs, universities, research
institutions, community-based organizations, traditional groups, etc., and
other types of assistances” (Royat 2002: 15).
This call was ultimate intention of the Bank intervention (Cammack
2004:199). Two prominent WB economists, Klaus Deininger and Hans Binswanger,
clearly re-articulate the Bank’s agenda, which is independent of any
client’s request. The agendas are: “to enhance investment by clarifying
property rights and establishing an institutional framework that guarantees
the security of these rights; to increase efficiency by facilitating
increased transferability of land (use) rights in rental and possibly sales
markets; and to improve the integration of land and other (financial)
markets. In addition, governments can consider imposing a land tax and
establishing land information systems” (Deininger and Binswanger
1999:265).
These agendas are firmly determined before they hire any experts or
consultants to make any studies to design a specific national government
project. Any studies that they and their consultants make have been oriented
towards enhancing the WB as a knowledge-based institution and producing what
Goldman (2001, 2006) calls authoritative knowledge. In order to establish
what it proclaims itself in World Development Report 1998-99, the globe’s ‘knowledge bank,’ it mobilizes resources (money, experts,
information, network, etc.) to create innovative knowledge production (Mehta
2001, Goldman 2001; King 2002). The produced knowledge not only reaffirms
their main agenda, but in turn poses their agenda as authoritative. The WB
Indonesia land administration projects have produced knowledge in various
forms such as study reports, discussion papers, workshop proceedings, etc.
through employing experts. This is not to say that there is no any critical
thinking produced, nor that there are no alternative agendas posed by hired
experts, but the WB has particular ways to use knowledge produced by various
activities that they assigned, and their decision-making processes are based
on selected and particular knowledge compatible with their
strategy.
III. Global network to promote pro-market land policy reform
The WB’s land projects are not unique to Indonesia. The Thailand Land
Titling Project starting in 1984 was their pilot project. The project partners are the Department of Land - the Royal Thai
Government, the WB, and the government of Australia
(AusAID). The overall project goal was to strengthen the
institutional capacity of the Department of Land by providing training and
expertise in cadastral surveying and mapping, title deeds issuance, land
valuation, and information technology. Now the WB has completed four
five-year phases, which concluded in 2004, and started the last phase of
twenty-five year project. At completion, it will have delivered
approximately 13 million titles to Thai landowners. Perhaps for
promotional purposes, the project received the World Bank Award for
Excellence in 1997. In various papers, World Bank, AusAID, and the
consultants promote the Thailand Land Titling Project as an outstanding
success story that acts as a benchmark for land administration and
managements and also for inter-agency cooperation (e.g. Rattanabirabongse
et al 1998, Feder and Nishio 1999, Ausaid 2000, 2001, Bowman 2004, Burn
2004).[7] WB claims that the Thailand Land Titling Project
“has led to its involvement in this area (sic) and over 50 land titling
projects world wide are under implementation ... the Thailand Land Titling
Programme [has] become standard for the World Bank and for some bilateral
donors including for example, USAID” (Holstein and Munro, “International
Impact of the Thailand Land Titling Programme”, Department of Lands,
Ministry of Interior, 2003, as quoted by William 2003:12).
After more than 20 years since their pilot project in Thailand, there are
increasing expenditures to make the land markets work through expanding land
titling, improving land management and institution, and reforming land
policies. Recent data unveiled by Bell (2006), the WB staff, shows the
magnitude of their efforts (see Table 1 and 2).
Table 1: Lending for dedicated land administration projects (US
Million)
Region |
Under supervision |
FY01- FY06 |
FY95-FY00 |
Before FY95 |
AFR |
48 |
48 |
46 |
|
EAP |
124 |
129 |
219 |
30 |
ECA |
451 |
426 |
109 |
80 |
LAC |
447 |
430 |
386 |
29 |
MNA |
- |
- |
- |
33 |
SAR |
5 |
5 |
|
|
Total |
1,074 (sic) |
1,037 (sic) |
760 |
172 |
Source: World Bank, Lending Database, 2006 as quoted in Bell (2006).
Table 2: Number of projects with land administration component/s
Region |
FY01- FY06 |
FY95-FY00 |
Before FY95 |
AFR |
28 |
15 |
16 |
EAP |
13 |
9 |
9 |
ECA |
16 |
10 |
3 |
LAC |
8 |
9 |
13 |
MNA |
3 |
3 |
5 |
SAR |
6 |
3 |
5 |
Total |
74 |
49 |
51 |
Source: World Bank, Lending Database, 2006 as quoted in Bell (2006).
Note:
Table 1 displays total World Bank lending for land administration by fiscal
year (FY) and region. It highlights a significant, though regionally highly
uneven, increase in total lending with the total amount of lending under
supervision currently standing at $1.1 billion. Total commitments in FY01-06
were above $1 billion, compared to $760 million in FY95-00, and only $172
million before FY95. However, the regional distribution is not uniform, with
two regions, Europe and Central Asia Region (ECA) and Latin America and
Caribbean Region (LAC), making up almost 90% of the size of the portfolio,
followed by East Asia and Pacific Region (EAP), and virtually no lending in
Africa (AFR), South Asia Region (SAR), and Middle East North Africa Region
(MNA). One of the key reasons for such a vast difference is that the
background work needed to underpin land administration projects in the MNA
has really only just started. Given the importance of land policy for a wide
range of situations, plus the Bank’s shift from project- towards
policy-based lending, it is not surprising to find an increasing number of
projects with land policy or administration components. Table 2 illustrates
that the number of these interventions amounted to 74 in FY01-06.
The WB is not the only actor to fund these land administration projects.
Jointly with the two regional banks (Inter-American Development Bank and
Asian Development Bank), and donor agencies from various developed
countries (DFID, GTZ, EU, DANIDA, USAID), the World Bank manages more than
one hundred loan and grant based land administration projects in more that
50 countries in Asia, Latin America and Africa and post-communist
countries.[8]These projects also reflect huge prospects for land administration
business. An advisor for the WB exposes the strategic link between land administration
projects and business in land administration in his paper “Mapping the
Business Processes Before Mapping the Ground” (Azad 2000: 16).[9]Tony Burns, Managing Director, Land Equity International Pty Ltd, a
leading Australian consultant firm in land administration, describes how
land administration in developing countries is a very good business. At
the close of his keynote address in the 2001 World Land Registration
Congress, Brisbane, Australia, he stated:
“There is no question in my mind that there is a market for strengthening
land administration systems – a market that is growing strongly. Even after
many years in the business, I never cease to be surprised by the range of
organizations, range of individuals – not only the traditional surveyors,
lawyers and records management professionals, but other specialists
including planners, and social and environmental scientists – and the range
of clients that is active in the marketplace.
… I see a very bright future for the Australian industry” (Burns 2001:
16).
It is absolutely true that land administration is a huge market but the
land administration market is not an open market by any means. The market is
restricted only to members of a closed network: the WB and other
international donor agencies, higher officials in government agencies, and
international/national consultant-cum-academic.[10] The network is directed by a very influential “epistemic community,”
to use Hass’s (2002) term,[11] in order to create pro-market land policies in developing and
ex-communist countries: the WB’s Thematic Group on Land Policy and
Administration (usually called The Land Thematic Group) and International
Federation of Surveyors (FIG).
The Land Thematic group is composed of “about 120 specialists with a wide
range of professional background working on issues related to rights of
lands and the control of access to land, and the use and disposal of its
associated natural resources to promote economically efficient, socially
equitable and environmentally sustainable development. The goal of this
group is to provide a forum to exchange ideas and experiences, and technical
and financial support to studies on priority issues and new approaches in
land policy.”[12] FIG is a federation of national surveyor associations and the only
international body that represents all surveying disciplines. It is an
UN-recognized non-governmental organization (NGO) and its aim is “to ensure
that the disciplines of surveying and all who practice them meet the needs
of the markets and communities that they serve. It realizes its aim by
promoting the practice of the profession and encouraging the development of
professional standards” (FIG 2004).[13] The core of network activities is dedicated to developing
authoritative knowledge on land administration and management. The network
develops and maintains authoritative knowledge through mainly grant and loan
related activities, and also via knowledge production such as teaching in
academic institution, doing research and publications, professional
trainings, workshops, publication, seminars and conferences, etc. They
develop some common platforms and package them as official documents – they
used United Nations in the title of some declarations in order to make them
seem more authoritative. For example, the 1996 UN-FIG Bogor Declaration on
Cadastral Reform[14] and the 1999 UN-FIG Bathurst Declaration Land Administration for
Sustainable Development.[15] In 2001, the network set up the “International Land Registration
Association”[16] with a single mission: ”to promote excellence in land registration
around the world.” Their vision is “(t)o share information, knowledge and
experiences through partnership with Association members, to benchmark and
improve developed land registration systems and provide advice and
assistance to jurisdictions developing or establishing secure, efficient
land registration systems,” with a primary goal “(t)o become the pre-eminent
world body for land registration recognized as an authoritative source of independent knowledge and advice.” (Italics added by NFR).
IV. Denaturalize the benevolent rhetoric
It is clear now that the WB’s land projects have propagated market
ideology, and used benevolent rhetoric to convince its government-clients.
Efforts to promote pro-market land policies emerge from a pro-market
critique of historical (state-directed) land policies that have increased in
prevalence since its inception at the end of the Cold War. They have
manifested in four broad policy types: privatization and individualization
of public/communal lands, privatization and individualization of property
rights in state and collective farms in (ex)communist and capitalist
settings, promotion of land rental markets, and promotion of land sales
(Borras 2006).
Using the perspective as outlined in the introduction, I critically
understand why Joko Walijatun and Christ Grant (the high official of
National Land Agency and team leader of AusAID consultants from
BHP-Enginering, Australia) confidently claim “(t)he LAP is thus not so much
a project but a new way of life. This new way of life will begin
to emerge as the systematic registration activities proceeds and the market
economy in land begins to grow” (Walijatun and Grant
1996:8. Italics added by NFR). In another work, Grant
reaffirms the idea that (l)and titling is however a long term program aimed
at bringing about reforms to the national system of land
administration. Thus it is not a series of activities and procedures, which
will disappear once the time or the budget has expired. Rather it is a
series of activities and procedures, which while initially developmental,
must progressively become embedded into the routine activities of the
agency. To be successful, people and institutions need to change. This change needs to be driven by leaders with vision so that the project
becomes a ‘way of life’. The challenge for the individuals responsible for project implementation
is to provide the management of the change through better institutional
linkages and integration” (Grant 1999:6. Italics added by
NFR).
In claiming that the project becomes a ‘way of life’, its implementers
expect that they can convince and reach broader audience and represent the
interests of a whole society. The World Bank land projects are also popular
and acceptable for the government clients because they claim to improve
economic growth and reduce poverty, as shown in their famous book, “Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction, a World Bank Policy
Research Report” (World Bank 2003). The document written by Klaus Deininger (economist
in the WB’s Development Research Group) has already become a reference
document for staff in the bank and partner institutions, key to the
construction of land policies in many developing countries in the years to
come, and also influencing debates around contemporary land policies. Shared
with Deininger, pro-market promoters such as Hernando de Soto (2000)
confidently argue that land titling can reduce poverty, but land titling by
itself is not a sufficient condition. It is typical to say the project will
reduce poverty only if (a) a variety of enabling preconditions are met, (b)
needed complementary components are included, and (c) beneficiaries are
consciously targeted (Bledsoe, 2006).
WB always justifies the project with the rhetoric of poverty reduction
because of their mandate “Our Dream is a World Free of Poverty.” The problem
is always the yawning gap between their claim and performance. To evaluate
the effect of land registration on its own terms will be useful as
constructive feedback for the project designers and implementers. The WB
hired researchers to conduct evaluation studies to assess processes and the
results of land titling under the Indonesia Land Administration Project
(Hardjono 1999 and SMERU 2002). Soerendra (2006) conducted research on the
effect of land titling on the living conditions of urban poor in slum area.
Research shows that the price of lands significantly increased after
titling, and there is increasing trend to sell the lands too. With the
official deed, the land owners feel more secure about the status of their
land, but there are also insecurities created in the titling process,
because they produce a new category “unknown land” (tanah tidak dikenal), meaning that the land agency can not provide the landowner with a deed,
because the applicant, who is the current landholder, cannot
administratively prove that they are the owner of the land. This evidence
proves that the project broke the promise that they will use alternative
methods in recognizing the existing landholders. After the project finished,
there was little evidence that poor people use land as collateral to access
credit from the bank. From both sets of evaluations, I conclude here that
the project facilitates the sale of land, but will not necessarily reduce
poverty through titling.
I will also use the debate on the effects of Thailand Land Titling
Projects not only to address the gaps between the project’s claims and
what happened in the ground, but also to show different perspectives used
by different parties to reach different conclusions. Studies by World Bank
economists provide convincing results that land registration massively
implemented by the Thailand Land Titling Project positively affects
financial development and economic growth (Byamugisha 1999a, 1999b. See
also Feder and Nishio 1998). There is a strong need, however, to examine
the on-the-ground effects of the titling program from the peasant’s
perspective that will illustrate critical effects of such programs that
may easily be lost and ignored by abstract analysis of aggregate data. An
official study conducted by WB East Asia and Pacific Region
Office, Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets, and Collateralized
Lending, shows “(t)he risks of land titling include the concentration of land
and increased landlessness due to distress sales that occur after the
marketability of land increases but before safety nets are strengthened
and the incomes of the poor improve”, and they claimed that ”(t)he socioeconomic impact assessment of the program in Thailand
revealed neither an increase in land concentration nor an increase in
landlessness in project areas.” (World Bank, 2004:iii. Italics added by NFR)
It may be the case, as Feder and Nishio (1998) and Byamugisha (1999a,
1999b) argue, that there is financial development and increasing economic
growth because of the project. But ignoring negative effects on the rural
poor leaves significant social costs out of the calculation. Worse, it begs
the key question of who benefits from the process at what (and whose) cost.
Some scholar activists such as Leonard and Ayutthaya (2003) and (Miyake
2003) provide counter-arguments based on the on-the-ground data. Leonard and
Ayutthaya show that
“it is difficult to see in practice how increased land prices have
benefited the poor and the landless. For one thing, high prices increase the
barriers to access land for the landless, including new generations of
farmers. The acquisition of land itself becomes a major long-term debt for
new landowners, which diverts a substantial proportion of future income into
mortgage repayments. Where prices rise sharply out of line with local
incomes, the exclusion of poor purchasers is inevitable. A more fundamental
problem relates to the commodification of land, the process of transforming
it into a freely tradable asset. This process encourages the purchase of
land by wealthier groups. As stated above, the very existence of title can
vastly increase the value of land. This in itself creates a significant
incentive for rich entrepreneurs to buy up untitled land, pay their
registration dues, and make a very quick profit” (Leonard and Ayutthaya
2003: 10).
They note that land titling also permitted urban speculators to buy up
formerly collective village lands, without villagers’ knowledge, leave them
idle and use them as collateral for massive loans at the height of
Thailand’s real estate bubble. As a consequence of the titling program,
tenure security decreased for some peasants, while the land
was used to secure speculative loans, ultimately resulting in large-scale
default. Miyake confirms their observation and shows that the titling
project created two fundamental causes of today’s land conflict in northern
Thailand; the commercialization and privatization of communal land, and the
system of private property rights that carries the concept of
exclusion.
“Supported by legal rights, land became a secure commodity, and a lot of
capitalist bought it for speculation and left idle, while the poor farmers
lost land. In addition, the penetration of commercialism in rural areas also
worsened the life level of local farmers. Traditionally, with the concept of
sharing and mutuality, the problem of landlessness and poverty has been
mitigated. However the concept of private property right of exclusion did
not allow any room for the traditional way. By the economic crisis in 1997,
the villagers find it harder and harder to make ends meet on the one hand,
and the more and more land plots were abandoned in Lamphun Province on the
other. Contesting for use rights of such uncultivated land, landless
villagers have instigated the direct action of taking it and cultivating it.
(Miyake 2003:15)
Because of this new property regime, the police arrested 33 farmers who
illegally trespassed on new private property. But as reported by Miyake
“(w)hile the villagers negotiate with the dominant group, they continue to
cultivate the land because they know by now that the legal right to access
to land cannot be given easily to the poor farmers” (Miyake 2003:16).
Discussion on the Thailand case opens up an important lesson that efforts
“to universalize the interests of one social sector to the whole community”
(Bello et al 1994:3) is never complete and always contradictory in
character. There is no guarantee that the hegemonic efforts in homogenizing
property right system will be fully welcomed by targeted people. There a
always space of resistance where some groups of marginalized/victimized
people and their allies conduct collective actions, such as land occupation,
to challenge and critique the newly imposed property systems. In the
Thailand case, the critiques are framed and amplified by a group of peasant
movement leaders, NGOs and concerned scholars:
“The land administration project of the Bank – including surveys, mapping,
cadastres, registries and granting of individual, alienable titles – while
they try to address long-standing demand by various rural groups for
security of tenure, are designed primarily to create the conditions for
“functioning land markets,” and all to frequently result in a massive or
on-going sell-off of land, in the re-concentration of property and in
increase in conflicts inside our communities, as we have seen in the case of
Thailand” (Final Declaration of International Seminar on the Negative Impact
of World Bank Market Based Land Reform, in Barros et al 2003:408).
IV. Conclusion and notes for future research
My conclusions on the role of the World Bank land projects in promoting
pro-market land regularization are twofold. Firstly, the WB land projects
are not only a bundle of projects, but systematic and long-term efforts to
homogenize the land property regime in developing and ex-communist
countries. In a country such as Indonesia and Thailand where radical
effort to address unequal land distribution has essentially been denied as
a main strategy for rural development, the WB land projects are seductive
because they naturalize the unequal power and land distribution through
complete overhaul of land administrations, managements and policies to
achieve economic growth and poverty eradication, which are two development
mantras of government administrations in developing countries. Second, the
stories about the effects of the projects in Indonesia and Thailand
indicate that more systematic and empirical research is needed to make the
effects of the regularization visible to anyone promoting access to land
and other resources for rural villagers landless as main strategy for
eradicating persistent poverty. The previous researches amplify
Baraclough’s critical observation that “(R)egistering land titles and facilitating … transactions between willing
sellers and willing buyers do not by themselves change power relationships
in favour of the rural poor. In many situations, such policies are likely
to reinforce agrarian structures by providing large landholders and
speculators with additional legal protection, while leaving the bargaining
power of the poor unchanged or diminished.” (1999:33)
In his article “What the World Bank Means by Poverty Reduction, and Why it
Matters” Cammack (2004) critiques WB‘s poverty reduction agendas, noting
that “while the Bank’s commitment to poverty reduction is real, within
limits, it is conditional upon, and secondary to, a broader goal. Its
principal objective is the systematic transformation of social relations and
institutions in the developing world, in order to generalize and facilitate
proletarianization and capitalist accumulation on a global scale, and build
specifically capitalist hegemony through the promotion of legitimating
schemes of community participation and country ownership” (Cammack
2004:190). Cammack with resonates with recent interpretations of Karl
Marx’s notion of “primitive” or “original accumulation”, which has
reinvigorated various new research agendas mainly in political economy,
geography, political ecology and development studies (Glassman 2006).
Traditional interpretations of “primitive accumulation” conceived of it as a
one-time historical phenomenon of dispossession, creating a “free” labor
force. In contrast, newer interpretations argue that capitalist
accumulation depends on the on-going, often violent, exclusion of
competitors from resources (Perelman 2000, De Angelis 1999, 2001).
David Harvey has made major contributions to this interpretation, using
“accumulation by dispossession” to explain current patterns of global
capitalist expansion (2003). Under the current moment of
neoliberalism, he claims, privatization and commodification take myriad
forms, through which capitalists actively manufacture these new forms and
realms of proletarization. Following Polanyi’s “double movement” (1944),
Harvey (2003) argues that accumulation by dispossession also generates
social movements to confront its depredations. Moreover, when social
movements erect barriers to capital, capitalist institutions move to
dismantle these barriers. Capital institutions also push the state to use
its coercive powers to create conditions conducive to further enclosure
and exclusion (Harvey 2005).
Employing that theoretical discussion, it should be important research
agenda to examine the way in which various effects of the WB pro-market land
regularization efforts, intersecting with various existing government
agrarian policies and practices create new constraints (or may be also
opportunities) for agrarian movement groups who challenge the existing
regimes of capital accumulation and repression, and promote redistributive
and restitutive land reform policies for landless peasants and indigenous
peoples. Take Indonesia as an example, peasant and indigenous movements
demanding land and other agrarian reforms have emerged across the nation
since the end of Suharto’s authoritarian regime in the late 1990s, and the
shifts to democratic and decentralized government during 2000 until now.
Indonesia’s resurgence of movements is particularly striking in light of the
agrarian struggles and massacres of the mid-1960s, the repression of
political activity under Suharto, and the massive dispossessions of land and
resources experienced during Suharto’s 32-year regime (Li 2000, 2001,
Aspinal 2004, Lucas and Warren 2005). ***
Berkeley, February 15, 2006
Bibliography
AusAID. 2000, Improving Access to Land and Enhancing the Security of Land Rights: A
Review of Land Titling and Land Administration Projects, Quality Assurance Series No. 20.
______. 2001. Undertaking Land Administration Project:
Sustainability, Affordability, Operational efficiency and Good Practice
Guidelines. Quality Assurance Series No. 26.
Azad, Bijan. 2000. “Mapping the Business Processes Before Mapping the
Ground: The Strategic Link to Improve Land Administration”, Washington, The
World Bank, Land and Real Estate Initiative, Background Series No. 10, June
2000.
National Land Agency and Land Administration System Australia.
1993. Project Preparation Report. Indonesia Land Administration Project. Laporan Persiapan Project. Project Administrasi Pertanahan –
Indonesia. Jakarta: Badan Pertanahan Nasional.
Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Nasional (BAPPENAS). Nd. Kerangka Kebijakan Pertanahan Nasional. In http://www.landpolicy.org and http://www.bktrn.org/article_document/Kerangka%20Kebijakan%20Pertanahan%20Nasional_Isi%20Lengkap.pdf (Accessed on December 6, 2006)
Barros, F. Sergio Sauer and Stephan Schwartzman (eds). 2003. The Negative Impacts of World Bank Market Based Land Reform. Action Aid, Bank Information Center, Christian Aid, Development and
Peace, Environmental Defense, Ford Foundation.
Barraclough, S. (1999) ‘Land ReforminDeveloping Countries’. UNRISD
Discussion Paper 101. Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social
Development.
Behuria, Sutanu. 1994. “Some Aspects of Land Administration in Indonesia:
Implication for Bank Operations”, Asian Development Bank, Occasional Papers
No. 10. Manila. Asian Development Bank.
Bell, Keith Clifford. 2006 World Bank Support for Land Administration and Management: Responding to the
Challenges of the Millennium Development Goals”. Paper presented at the
XIII FIG Congress in Munich, Germany, 8-13 October 2006.
Bello, Walden, Shea Cunningham and Bill Rau, 1994. Dark Victory, The United States, Structural Adjustment and Global
Poverty. Amsterdam. The Transnational Institute.
Borras, Saturnino M. 2006. “The Underlying Assumptions, Theory, and
Practice of Neoliberal Land Policies”. In Peter Rosset, Rajeev
Patel, and Michael Courville (eds), Promised Land:. Competing Visions of Agrarian Reform. Oakland: Food First Books.
Bowman, Chakriya. 2004. “Thailand Land Titling Project”, a paper
for Scaling Up Poverty Reduction: A Global Learning Process and Conference,
Shanghai, May 25.27, 2004
Burns, Antony. 2001. “The Synergy of Global Cooperation – Why Australian
Industry has Prevailed in a Development Environment”, Keynote Address for
World Land Registration Congress, Brisbane, Australia, 11-16 November
2001.
______ 2004. Thailand’s 20 year Program to Title Rural Land, World Development Report 2005, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2005/Resources/burns_thailand_land_titling.pdf (Accessed on December 6, 2006)
Byamugisha, Frank. K. 1999. The Effects of Land Registration on Financial
Development and Economic Growth: A Theoretical and Conceptual
Framework, The World Bank, East Asia and Pacific Region, Rural
Development and Natural Resources Sector Unit. Policy Research Working Paper
Series No. 2240.
______ 1999. How Land Registration Affects Financial Development
and Economic Growth in Thailand. The World Bank, East Asia and Pacific
Region, Rural Development and Natural Resources Sector Unit. Policy Research
Working Paper Series No. 2241.
Byamugisha, Frank, and Wael Zakout. 2000. “World Bank Support for
Land-Related Projects in Developing Countries, Experiences and Implications
for International Cooperation”, Paper Prepared for the UN Regional
Cartographic Conference for Asia and the Pacific (UNRCC-AP), Kuala Lumpur,
Malaysia April 11-14, 2000
Cammack, Paul. 2004. “What the World Bank Means by Poverty Reduction, and
Why it Matters”. New Political Economy. Vol. 9, No. 2. pp.
189-211.
De Angelis, M. 1999. Marx’s theory of primitive accumulation: A
suggested reinterpretation.
www.homepages.uel.ac.uk/M.DeAngelis/PIMACCA.htm.
______ 2001 Marx and primitive accumulation: The continuous character of
capital’s“enclosures.” www.thecommoner.org.
______ 2004 Separating the doing and the deed: Capital and the continuous
character of enclosures. Historical Materialism,
12(2):57-87.
Deininger, Klaus and Hans Binswanger. 1999. The Evolution of The World
Bank’s Land Policy: Principles, Experience, and Future Challenges. The World Bank Research Observer. Vol. 14, no. 2 (August 1999), pp. 247–76.
Deininger, Klaus. 2003. Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction.
World Bank Policy Research Report. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
De Soto, Hernando. 2000. Mystery of Capital, Why
Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic
Books.
Feder, Gershon and Akihiko Nishio. 1999. “The Benefits of Land
Registration and Titling: Economic and Social Perspectives”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 15. No. 1, pp 25.
Hass, Peter. M.. 1992. Introduction: Epistemic Communities and
International Policy Coordination. Internal Organization. Vol.
46 (1), pp. 1-37.
Hancock, Graham. 1989. Lords of Poverty: The Power, Prestige, and Corruption of the
International Aid Business. New York: Atlantic Monthly Press
George, Susan. 1992. The Debt Boomerang: How Third World Debt Harms Us All.
London: TNI and Pluto Press.
Goldman, Michael. 2001. “The birth of a Discipline: Producing Authoritative
Green Knowledge, World Bank-style. Ethnography, Vol. 2, No. 2,
191-217.
______ 2005 Imperial Nature: The World Bank and Struggles for Social Justice in the
Age of Globalization. Yale, Yale University Press, 2005
Glassman, J. 2006. Primitive Accumulation, Accumulation by
Dispossession, Accumulation by ‘Extra-economic’ Means. Progress in Human Geography 30(5):608–625
Grant, Chris. 1999. “Lessons from SE Asian Cadastral Reform, Land Titling
and Land Administration Projects in Supporting Sustainable Development in
the Next Millennium”. A paper presented at the UN-FIG Conference on Land
Tenure and Cadastral Infrastructures for Sustainable Development, Melbourne,
Australia, 25-27 October 1999.
Hardjono, Joan. 1999. A Social Assessment of The Land Certification
Program, the Indonesia Land Administration Project. Jakarta: World Bank
Office.
Harvey, David. 2003. The New Imperialism. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
______ .2005. A Brief History of Neoliberalism.Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Hass, Peter. 1992. “Introduction: Epintemic Communities and International
Policy Policy Coordination”, International Organization. Vol 46.
No. 1. pp. 21-26.
Heryani, E. and C. Grant. 2004. “Land Administration in Indonesia.” A paper
for 3rd FIG Regional Conference. Jakarta, Indonesia.
International Federation of Surveyors, Information 2003 -2006.
Leaflet. http://www.fig.net/general/leaflet_english_2004.pdf (Accessed on December 6, 2006)
International Land Registration Association – Prospectus, 2002. http://www3.telus.net/lorenleader/papers/ilra_prospectus.pdf (Accessed on December 6, 2006)
King, Kenneth 2002 “Banking on Knowledge: the new knowledge projects of the
World Bank”. Compare Volume 32, Number 3 / October 01, p
311 – 326.
Konsorsium Pembaruan Agraria. 1996a. Land Disputes: Strawberries of Development. KPA's first Memorandum on Land Administration Project.
Bandung: KPA (Consortium for Agrarian Reform).
______ 1996b. Our Land is Not for Sale. KPA's Second Memorandum on Land Administration Project. Bandung: KPA (Consortium for Agrarian Reform).
______ 1997a. To Ignore or to Engange NGO’s? KPA's Third Memorandum on Land
Administration. Bandung: KPA (Consortium for Agrarian Reform).
______ 1997b. No! for Communal Land Registration. KPA's Third Memorandum on Land Administration. Bandung: KPA (Consortium for Agrarian Reform).
Leonard, Rebeca and Kingkorn Narutarakul Na Ayuthaya. 2003 Thailand’s Land
Titling Project: Securing Land for the Poor? In Barrios, Flavia, Segoi
Sauer, and Sthephan Schartzman (eds) The Negative Impacts of World Bank Market-Based Land Reform. Sao Paolo: Comissao Pastoral da erra (CPT)/Movimento dos Trabalhadores
Rural Sem Terra (MST/FoodFirst Informaton and Action Network (FIAN).
Li, Tania. 2001 “Masyarakat Adat, Difference, and the limits of recognition
in Indonesia’s forest zone” Modern Asian Studies 35(3):645-676.
_____ 2000 “Articulating Indigenous Identity in Indonesia: Resource
Politics and the Tribal Slot” Comparative Studies in Society and History
42(1):149-179.
Mehta, Lyla. 2001. The World Bank and its Emerging Knowledge
Empire. Human Organization 60 (2): 189-96.
Miyake, Yuki. 2003. Contesting Rights over Land: A Case Study of Landless
Farmers’ Social Movement in Lamphun Province. A paper for Politics of the
Commons: Articulating Development and Strengthening Local Practices, Chiang
Mai, Thailand, July 11-14, 2003.
Nasution, Lutfi Ibrahim 2004. ”Status of the Implementation of the Bogor
Declaration”, Keynote Address for 3rd FIG Regional Conference - Jakarta,
Indonesia, October 3-7, 2004
_____. 2002. “What Land Administration and Titling Project Has Done to
Sustaibale land Management? A Case in Indonesia with LAP Phase I”. A paper
to World Bank Regional Workshop on Land Issues Program,
Asia Region. June 4 - 6, 2002. Hotel Cambodiana, Phnom Penh,
Cambodia
Perelman, Michael. 2000. The Invention of capitalism: Classical political economy and the secret
history of primitive accumulation, Durham & London: Duke University Press.
Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation, The Political and Economi Origin of Our Time. Boston, Beacon Press.
Rattanabirabongse, V., R.A. Eddington, A. E Burns, and K. G. Nettle. 1998.
“The Thailand Land Titling Project Thirteen Years of Experience,” Land Use Policy, Vol. 15 No.1. pp. 2-23.
Rebeca and Kingkorn Narintarakul Na Ayutthaya. 2003. “Thailand’s Land
Titling Programme: Securing land for the poor?” Paper presented at “Politics
of the Commons” International Conference, Regional Centre for Sustainable
Development , Chiang Mai University, Thailand, July 11-14 2003.
Royat, Sujana. 2002. “World Bank Regional Workshop on Land Issues Program,
Asia Region. June 4 - 6, 2002. Hotel Cambodiana, Phnom Penh,
Cambodia.
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition
Have Failed. New Haven, CT. Yale University Press.
SMERU. 2002. An Impact Evaluation of Systematic Land Titling under the Land
Administration Project (LAP). Jakarta: SMERU.
Soehendera, Djaka 2006 Sertipikat Tanah dan Orang Miskin: Kasus Kampung
Rawa Jakarta. Jakarta: Departement of antropology, University of Indonesia.
Unpublished Dissertation.
Williams, Shaun. 2003. “International Conference on ‘The Thailand Land
Titling Program: Challenges to Land Administration.’ Back to Office
Report”, Programme of Advisory Support Services for Rural Livelihoods, The
UK Department for International Development (DFID) - Technical
Output. 14 April 2003.
Williamson, Ian and Don Grant. 2002. “United Nations – FIG
Bathurst Declaration on Land Administration for Sustainable Development:
Development and Impact”. A paper delivered to FIG XXII International
Congress, Washington, D.C. USA, April 19-26 2002
World Bank. 1994. Indonesia Land Administration Project, Staff Appraisal Report. Washington. World Bank, Agriculture Operations Division, Country
Department III, East Asia and Pacific Region: 67 pages.
_____. 1994. Indonesia, Environment and Development.
Washington. The World Bank.
_____. 2004. Project Appraisal Document on A Proposed Loan in the Amount of US$ 32.8
Million and A Credit in the Amount of SDR 21.9 (US$ 32.8 Million
Equivalent) to The Government of Republic of Indonesia for A Land
Management and Policy Development Project. Washington. The World Bank. Rural Development and Natural Resources
Sector Unit East Asia and Pacific Region. Report No: 28
178-IND
_____. 2004. Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets, and Collateralized
Lending. Washington: The World Bank, East Asia and Pacific Region Office.
_____. “Indonesia Policy Brief: Ideas for the Future. Land Policy, Management and
Administration”. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTINDONESIA/Resources/Publication/280016-1106130305439/617331-1110769011447/810296-1110769045002/LandPolicy.pdf. (Accessed on December 6, 2006)
[1] In the appendix, I briefly sketch the projects and their
results.
[2] The full text can be found in http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTINDONESIA/Resources/Publication/280016-1106130305439/617331-1110769011447/810296-1110769045002/LandPolicy.pdf. They also provide the Bahasa Indonesia version in: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTINDONESIA/Resources/Publication/280016-1106130305439/617331-1110769011447/810296-1110769073153/Landpolicy.pdf. Last accessed is December 6, 2006
[3] I will discuss the Thailand Land Titling Project in Part III of
the paper.
[4] I have started to monitor the WB’s Indonesia land projects
during my activities in the Consortium for Agrarian Reform (Konsorsium
Pembaruan Agraria or KPA) as Chair person in 1995-2002. There are four
memorandums that KPA released concerning the project (Konsorsium
Pembaruan Agraria 1996a, 1996b, 1997a, and 1997b).
[5] In the same year, Sutanu Behuria (1994) produced a policy
analysis for and published by the Asia Development Bank, which
explains that “the implementation of a large number of Bank-financed
and World-Bank financed projects across the sectors was seriously
affected by … land acquisition difficulties...” and “the Bank should
provide financial assistance to Indonesia to accelerate the process of
land registration and titling as well as provide technical assistance
for codifying and simplifying the laws and procedures with regard to
land transfers and use” (Behuria 1994: 10).
[6]
About so-called “Bogor Declaration” see part III.
[7] From 19-21 February 2003 Department of Lands (DoL) in the
Ministry of Interior of the Royal Thai Government (RTG) hosted a World
Bank, AusAID and FAO sponsored conference in Bangkok, “Thailand Land
Titling Programme - Challenges To Land Administration” attended by 200
delegates from the Asia, Central Europe and the Americas.
[8] For more recent (2005) and extensive list including DFID, GTZ,
EU, DANIDA, USAID projects, see http://www.landadmin.co.uk/Projects/Projects_1.htm (Last accessed on January 4, 2006).
[9] Azzad writes “… backed up by tangible results that, by standing
the traditional motto of land administration ‘Let’s map the ground so
that cadastral mapping and surveying can be more easily done’ on its
head and saying, “I have a land administration business process to
improve, how can I use land administration investments to do so?” we
can increase the effectiveness and efficiency of land registration and
cadastre investments significantly” (Azad 200:16).
[10] Some experts easily shift their positions, for example from
academic position in university into fellow in
international-consultant firms. For example, Ian Williamson and Don
Grant, who actively promote “Sustainable development is just rhetoric
without appropriate land administration systems” refer their positions
as professor in University of Melbourne, fellows in some international
consulting agencies in Australia, and have conducted research and
consultancy world-wide including for AusAID, WB, some major UN
international organization such as the United Nation - Department of
Economic and Social Affairs (UNDESA) - Division for Sustainable
Development - New York, UNDESA - Division for Statistics - New York;
The United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UNCHS) – Habitat -
Nairobi; the United Nation Food and Agricultural Organization (UNFAO)
– Rome, the UN Economic Commission for Africa (UNECA) - Addis Ababa.
See Williamson and Grant 2002. Another example is Keith Cliford Bell,
responsible person for supporting land administration projects
throughout the East Asia region, and also works in Cambodia,
Indonesia, Lao Peoples Democratic Republic, Philippines and Vietnam.
He joined the WB in 2003 after he worked for international consulting
agencies in Australia. Prior to this he held a range of senior
positions in Australian Government, including general manager in
Planning and Land management of the Australian Capital territory
Government, and Director of the National Land data Center in the
Australia Government.
[11] According Hass, “(a) epistemic community is a network of
professionals with recognized expertise and competence n a particular
domain and an authoritative claim to policy-relevant knowledge within
domain or issue-area. .. (T)hey have (1) a shared set of normative and
principled beliefs, which provide a value-based rationale for the
social action of community members; (2) shared causal beliefs, which
are derived from their analysis of practices leading or contributing
to a central set of problems in their domain and which then serve as
the basis for elucidating the multiple linkages between possible
policy actions and desired outcomes; (3) shared notions of validity –
that is, intersubjective, internally defined criteria for weighing and
validating knowledge in the domain of their expertise; and (4) a
common policy enterprise – that is, a set of common practices
associated with a set of problems to which their professional
competence is directed, presumably out of the conviction that human
welfare will be enhanced as a consequence” (Hass 1992:3).
[12] http://Inweb18.worldbank.org/ESSD/ardext.nsf/24ByDocName/AboutUs (accessed December 4, 2006). The Group is currently co-chaired
by Frank Fulgence K. Byamugisha (Principal Operations Officer in The
WB’s Rural Development & Natural Resource Sector Unit), and Klaus
W. Deininger (Economist with the WB’s Development Research Group). See
also www.worlbank.org/landpolicy/ (accessed December 4, 2006).
[13] For detail information on activities of this network
visit http://www.fig.net (accessed December 4, 2006).. See also International Federation
of Surveyors, Information 2003 -2006. http://www.fig.net/general/leaflet_english_2004.pdf (accessed December 4, 2006).
[14] The so-called “the Bogor Declaration” was prepared at an
Inter-Regional Meeting of Experts on Cadastre held in Bogor in 18-22
March 1996. The objective of the meeting was “to develop a document
setting out the desirable requirements and options for cadastral
systems of developing countries in the Asia and Pacific region and to
some extent globally.” It is interesting to underline how they claim
the meeting a “United Nations Interregional Meeting of Experts on the
Cadastre” among others because of the United Nations Department for
Development Support and Management Services (UN-DDSMS) are involved in
sponsoring the meeting, together with the Indonesian State Ministry
for Agrarian Affairs, the National Land Agency (BPN), the National
Coordination Agency for Surveys and Mapping (BAKOSURTANAL) and the
International Federation of Surveyors (FIG). The meeting also receives
funding from AusAID, the Australian agency for international
development. The meeting was attended by experts from Australia,
Bulgaria, Cambodia, People's Republic of China, Indonesia, Republic of
Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, the Philippines, South Africa, Sweden,
United Kingdom, Thailand and Vietnam. For full text, see http://www.sli.unimelb.edu.au/fig7/Bogor/BogorDeclaration.html (accessed November 4, 2006).
[15] The 1999 United Nations-FIG Bathurst Declaration on Land
Administration for Sustainable Development was prepared at an
International Workshop on Cadastral Infrastructures for Sustainable
Development in Bathurst, New South Wales, Australia, on 18-22 October
1999. The conference was organized jointly by the FIG and some United
Nations bodies (United Nations Department of Economic and Social
Affairs (DESA), Statistic Division, New York, United Nations -
Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Division for Sustainable
Development, New York; United Nations Centre for Human Settlements
(Habitat), Nairobi; United Nations Food and Agricultural Organization
(FAO), Rome; United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (UNECA),
Addis Ababa; World Bank, Washington DC; Meeting of Officials of Land
Administration (MOLA) under the direction of the United Nations
Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE); and Permanent Committee for
GIS Infrastructure for Asia and the Pacific (PCGIAP) which was created
by the United Nation Regional Cartographic Conference (UNRCC) for Asia
and the Pacific). The conference was attended by “40 experts in land
administration from 5 continents, 25 developing and developed
countries, 5 UN agencies and WB, and FIG.” For full text,
see http://www.sli.unimelb.edua.au/UNConf99/proceeding.htm. accessed December 4, 2006).
[16] The International Land Registration Association was created by the unanimous decision of delegates at the inaugural
World Land Registration Congress held in Brisbane, Australia in
November 2001. Instead of declaring individual or organizational
membership, they put name of states as their members. There 30 states
that was written in their prospectus, i.e. Australia (all States and
Territories), Brunei Darussalam, China, East Timor, England, Fiji,
France, Hong Kong, Hungary, Indonesia, Israel, Kiribati, Lithuania,
Macedonia, Mauritius, Namibia, New Brunswick (Canada), New Zealand,
Republic of Ireland, Samoa, Scotland, Singapore, South Africa, South
Korea, Spain, Swaziland, Switzerland, Uganda, Vietnam, and Wales. See:
International Land Registration Association – Prospectus, 2002. See:
International Land Registration Association, Prospectus 2002,http://www3.telus.net/lorenleader/papers/ilra_prospectus.pdf (accessed on November 5, 2006)
No comments:
Post a Comment